UNITED STATES v. ALUMINUM
COMPANY OF AMERICA
148 F.2d 416 (2d. Cir. 1945)
JUDGE LEARNED HAND. It does not follow because "Alcoa" had
such a monopoly that it "monopolized" the ingot market: it may not
have achieved monopoly; monopoly may have been thrust upon it. If it had been a
combination of existing smelters which united the whole industry and controlled
the production of all aluminum ingot, it would certainly have
"monopolized" the market. . . . We may start therefore with the
premise that to have combined ninety percent of the producers of ingot would
have been to "monopolize" the ingot market; and so far as concerns
the public interest, it can make no difference whether an existing competition
is put an end to, or whether prospective competition is 1945) prevented.
. . . Nevertheless, it is unquestionably true that from the very outset 'the courts have at least kept in
reserve the possibility that the origin of
a monopoly may be critical in determining its legality; and for this they had
warrant in some of the congressional debates which accompanied the passage of
the Act. . . . This notion has usually been expressed by saying that size does
not determine guilt; that there must be some "exclusion" of
competitors; that the growth must be something else than "natural" or
"normal"; that there must be a "wrongful intent," or some
other specific intent; or that some "unduly" coercive means must be
used. At times there has been emphasis upon the use of the active verb,
"monopolize," as the judge noted in the case at bar. .
. . A market may, for example, be so limited that it is impossible to produce
at all and meet the cost of production except by a plant large enough to supply
the whole demand. Or there may be changes in taste or in cost which drive out
all but one purveyor. A single producer may be the survivor out of a group of
active competitors, merely by virtue of his superior skill, foresight, and
industry. In such cases a strong argument can be made that, although, the
result may expose the public to the evils of monopoly, the Act does not mean to
condemn the resultant of those very forces which it is its prime object to
foster: finis opus coronat. The successful competitor, having been urged to
compete, must not be turned upon when he wins.
[As] Cardozo, J., in United States v. Swift & Co., 286 U.S. 106, p.
116,52 S. Ct. 460, 463, 76 L.Ed. 999. . . . said, "Mere size . . . is not
an offense against the Sherman Act unless magnified to the point at which it
amounts to a monopoly . . . but size carries with it an opportunity for abuse
that is not to be ignored when the opportunity is proved to have been utilized
in the past." "Alcoa's" size was "magnified" to make
it a "monopoly"; indeed, it has never been anything else; and its
size not only offered it an "opportunity for abuse," but it
"utilized" its size for "abuse," as can easily be shown.
It would completely misconstrue "Alcoa's" position in 1940 to
hold that it was the passive beneficiary of a monopoly, following upon an
involuntary elimination of competitors by automatically operative economic
forces. Already in 1909, when its last lawful monopoly ended, it sought to
strengthen its position by unlawful practices, and these concededly continued
until 1912. In that year it had two plants in New York, at which it produced
less than 42 million pounds of ingot; in 1934 it had five plants (the original
two, enlarged; one in Tennessee; one in North Carolina; one in Washington), and
its production had risen to about 327 million pounds, an increase of almost eight-fold.
Meanwhile not a pound of ingot had been produced by anyone else in the United
States. This increase and this continued and undisturbed control did not fall
undesigned into "Alcoa's" lap; obviously it could not have done so.
It could only have resulted, as it did result, from a persistent determination
to maintain the control, with which it found itself vested in 1912. There were
at least one or two abortive attempts to enter the industry, but
"Alcoa" effectively anticipated and forestalled all competition, and
succeeded in holding the field alone. True, it stimulated demand and opened new
uses for the metal, but not without making sure that it could supply what it
had evoked. There is no dispute as to this; "Alcoa" avows it as
evidence of the skill, energy and initiative with which it has always conducted
its business: as a reason why, having won its way by fair means, it should be
commended, and not dismembered. We need charge it with no moral derelictions
after 1912; we may assume that all its claims for itself are true. The only
question is whether it falls within the exception established in favor of those
who do not seek, but cannot avoid, the control of a market. It seems to us that
that question scarcely survives its statement. It was not inevitable that it
should always anticipate increases in the demand for ingot and be prepared to
supply them. Nothing compelled it to keep doubling and redoubling its capacity
before others entered the field. It insists that it never excluded competitors;
but we can think of no more effective exclusion than progressively to embrace
each new opportunity as it opened, and to face every newcomer with new capacity
already geared into a great organization, having the advantage of experience,
trade connections and the elite of personnel. Only in case we interpret
"exclusion" as limited to maneuvers not honestly industrial, but
actuated solely by a desire to prevent competition, can such a course,
indefatigably pursued, be deemed not "exclusionary." So to limit it
would in our judgment emasculate the Act; would permit just such consolidations
as it was designed to prevent.
We disregard any question of "intent." Relatively early in the
history of the Act-1905-Holmes, J., in Swift & Co. v. United States,
explained this aspect of the Act in a passage often quoted. Although the
primary evil was monopoly, the Act also covered preliminary steps, which, if
continued, would lead to it. These may do no harm of themselves; but if they
are initial moves in a plan or scheme which, carried out, will result in
monopoly, they are dangerous and the law will nip them in the bud. . . . In
order to fall within 5 2, the monopolist must have both the power to
monopolize, and the intent to monopolize. To read the passage as demanding any "specific,"
intent, makes nonsense of it, for no monopolist monopolizes unconscious of what
he is doing. So here, "Alcoa" meant to keep, and did keep, that
complete and exclusive hold upon the ingot market with which it started. That
was to 'monopolize" that market, however innocently it otherwise
proceeded. So far as the judgment held that it was not within 5 2, it must be
reversed.